C. T. Kurien and Rethinking Economics

Born in 1931, C. T. Kurien contributed to rethinking economics through his various writings, particularly books and his vision for a practical B.A degree in Economics at Madras Christian College (MCC), an autonomous college situated in Chennai, a port city in Southern India. Besides MCC, another institution he contributed to was Madras Institute of Development Studies (MIDS), a research-only institute, also in Chennai. Kurien passed away in July 2024 aged 93.

This blog post provides a brief introduction to Kurien鈥檚 life and economics.

Brief Life

While at school in Kerala, Kurien was struck by the glimpses of Indian socio-economic realities found in Minoo Masani鈥檚 Our India, which was a text for his English course. It was recommended that he study logic and history before undertaking a degree in economics; and so, Kurien pursued his Intermediate (today鈥檚 class 11 & 12) from St. Joseph鈥檚 College, Bengaluru between 1948 and 1950.

Kurien did his B.A (Hons.) Economics at MCC (1950-53). In an autographical discussion in Rethinking Economics: Reflections Based on a Study of the Indian Economy (1996), Kurien shares details regarding his academic life. As a BA student, Kurien had to study 6 papers and write one essay; in the first year, he had 鈥楶rinciples of Economics鈥 and 鈥楨conomic History鈥; and in his final year, he had 鈥楶ublic Finance鈥 and 鈥楻ural Economics鈥. The 鈥楶rinciples of Economics鈥 course dealt with the theory of consumer behaviour drawn from marginalist economists such as Lionel Robbins. It was in the 鈥楶ublic Finance鈥 course where the students were exposed to contemporary discussions related to the Indian Economy.

Since Madras University recognised BA (hons) as equivalent to an MA in Economics, Kurien was eligible for lectureship. And so, after his BA, he joined the teaching faculty at MCC in 1953. Kurien was to be associated with MCC for 25 years鈥攈e left MCC in 1978.[1] Between 1953 and 1958, Kurien (1996) identifies two debates, which took place in the pages of Economic Weekly that influenced him. First was VKRV Rao鈥檚 critique of Keynesian economics based on the standpoint of Indian specificities. The second was the debate on the choice of technique in relation to questions regarding planning. In the former, KN Raj, Joan Robinson, Amartya Sen, and others participated.

Taking a leave of absence from MCC, Kurien moved to Stanford University in 1958 to begin work on his PhD, which was completed in 1962. His teachers included H. Houthakker, K. Arrow, Irma Adelman, Hollis Chenery, Lorie Tarshis and Bernard Haley. Kurien鈥檚 Ph.D supervisor was Chenery, and when Chenery left to join the Kennedy administration, Moses Abramovitz became Kurien鈥檚 supervisor. Kurien鈥檚 Ph.D thesis was titled Factor Market Structure and Technological Characteristics  of an Underdeveloped Country: An Indian Case Study. The central argument was that there was a rational basis 鈥渇or factor market imperfections in underdeveloped countries, particularly those said to be characterised by surplus labour鈥 (p. 27).

In 1978, Kurien left MCC and joined MIDS as its director. MIDS was founded by Malcolm Adisheshiah in 1970 and in 1977 was reconstituted as an Indian Council for Social Science Research (ICSSR) institute. Kurien served as Chairman of MIDS from 1997 to 2003. At MIDS, he supervised ten PhD dissertations (for the list, see Appendix A). In 1996, Kurien received UGC鈥檚 Lifetime Achievement Award. In 2002, he served as the President of Indian Economic Association.

Rural Transformation

Kurien鈥檚 book Dynamics of Rural Transformation:  A Study of Tamil Nadu, 1950-1975 (1981) was a pioneering one in regional economics, and it was adapted as a model study for other states by ICSSR. Published in 1981, the book examined the nature of rural transformation in Tamil Nadu between 1950 and 1975.

Kurien outlines the following ways to interpret changes in Tamil Nadu鈥檚 rural economy.

  1. Commodity flow approach: this mostly involves the 鈥渃onversion of all quantities into value categories鈥︹ (p. 119). Within this, the commonly used methods are the neoclassical aggregate production function and the disaggregated input-output.
  2. Class approach: since classes are 鈥渃onceptual categories鈥, their usage allows for commenting on long-term changes. Moreover, when applied to studying short-term changes, the translation of 鈥渃onceptual categories into operational empirical categories鈥 have been found to be 鈥渄ifficult鈥 (p. 120). Kurien, here, refers to the debate between Ashok Rudra and Utsa Patnaik in 1971 in Economic & Political Weekly (p. 147, n. 4).
  3. Factor analysis: this 鈥渆nables an examination of the interrelationships among a set of variates to proceed towards the construction of a composite index out of the variety of variables鈥 (p. 120). Kurien probably picked this up from Adelman, one of his Stanford teachers; she co-authored with Cynthia Morris Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach in 1967.
  4. Cluster analysis: it 鈥減ermits one to group a set of variables or entities whose properties can be represented by a variety of variables, into more homogeneous subgroups鈥︹ (p. 120); this was used in his earlier work with Josef James which was published as Economic Change in Tamil Nadu 1960-1970 (1979).

Kurien eschews all these four approaches and prefers going with 鈥渁 deliberately chosen focus鈥 (p. 120) to make sense of rural transformation. In the book, he makes use of decile groups, Gini coefficients and concentration ratios. Kurien makes the issues in comparing various survey data very explicit and provides a rich description of the data sources. There are insightful discussions on cropping patterns in the districts versus the state (pp. 37-41), increased mechanization of agriculture (p. 35), increased consumption of fertilizers (p. 36), decline in rural real wages (p. 100).

Markets in Economic Theory

Kurien鈥檚 R.C. Dutt lectures on political economy, given in 1990, was published as a book in 1993. It was titled On Markets in Economic Theory and Policy.

While he has not made theoretical contributions to the notion of markets, as a student of development economics, Kurien has 鈥渢ried to understand the phenomenon of the market in the context of the evolution and transformation of economies鈥 (p. 7). He rightly observes that 鈥溾hile theory has the facility to make abstractions from reality, policy cannot abstract away from reality鈥 (p. 12). After stating that 鈥淸t]here are different theoretical traditions in economics鈥, Kurien draws our attention to the 鈥渢wo very broad traditions鈥 outlined by Amartya Sen: 鈥渢he 鈥榚thical鈥 and 鈥榚ngineering鈥 traditions (p. 8). Kurien鈥檚 standpoint is best captured by this sentence: 鈥渢he market must be considered both as a social institution and as embodying certain logical properties鈥 (p. 10).

In his lectures, Kurien focuses his attention on four thinkers: Adam Smith, Karl Marx, John Hicks, and Karl Polanyi. In this blog post, we shall restrict our attention to Kurien鈥檚 view of Adam Smith鈥攅specially because of the dominant view which incorrectly views Smith as a precursor of marginalist economics and a champion of free market.

Kurien rightly points out the state of affairs that Smith is not pleased with: guilds and restrictions on trade. Smith wished that people had the freedom to enter the market and compete. And, most importantly, 鈥溾mith鈥檚 position is that the exercise of self-love must be seen within the context of a kind of social relationship built on justice which includes protecting the weak and chastising the guilty鈥 (p. 15). Kurien makes his own position very explicit when he writes that he favours the 鈥渆thical tradition鈥he institutional approach鈥 (p. 11).

Traditions in Economics

Kurien鈥檚 engagement with various approaches in economics is visible in his Dynamics of Rural Transformation (1981), On Markets in Economic Theory and Policy (1993), and 鈥楬istory, Logic and Narrative in Pedagogy鈥 (2019)鈥攁 chapter in Pluralistic Economics and Its History, a book I co-edited with Ajit Sinha.

Drawing on Sen, Kurien (1993) places Socrates, Aristotle and Kautilya in the 鈥渆thical tradition鈥 and Walras in the 鈥渆ngineering tradition鈥 (p. 9). But in fact, Sen places Kautilya in the engineering tradition alongside Petty and Walras. Sen, in his slim book On Ethics and Economics (1987), writes: 鈥淭he 鈥榚ngineering鈥 approach also connects with those studies of economics which developed from the technique-oriented analysis of statecraft. Indeed, in what was almost certainly the first book ever written with anything like the title 鈥楨conomics鈥, namely Kautilya鈥檚 Arthasastra, the logistic approach to statecraft, including economic policy, is prominent鈥 (p. 5).

Such a distinction is a poor one because Smith鈥檚 political economy is a mix of logical and ethical considerations. More significantly, such a distinction is problematic because it obfuscates the truth鈥攖hat there exists contending paradigms within the so-called engineering tradition. For example, Ricardo is a classical political economist while Walras is a marginalist economics鈥攁nd both were concerned about ethical matters.

On the first point, Kurien also agrees. As he writes: 鈥渢here is no incompatibility between the ethical and engineering approaches鈥 and 鈥溾he tendency to think of the two traditions as mutually exclusive, and even as antagonistic 鈥 is an error and a pity鈥 (p. 9). Kurien also calls them the 鈥渋nstitutional approach鈥 and the 鈥渓ogical approach鈥 (p. 10).

In Kurien (2019), he begins by noting that economics teaching is dominated by neoclassical (I prefer marginalist) economics owing to the dominance of textbooks by Mankiw (and in the past, Samuelson and Marshall). While Kurien (1981) distinguished between the neoclassical production function and class analysis, his subsequent writings draw from Sen鈥檚 classification. In Kurien (2019), he calls the two approaches in economics as the 鈥渟ubstantive approach鈥 and the 鈥渇ormal approach鈥. He places Smith in the former and Ricardo, Jevons, Walras, Arrow, and Debreu in the latter.

Concluding Thoughts

Kurien had a life-long interest in the pedagogy of economics. In Kurien (2019), he recommended the inclusion of real-life issues, history of economic thought and economic history, and the collection and analysis of data in the economics curriculum. And so, when I sent him my book Macroeconomics: An Introduction (2021), which is built on my standpoint of contending (鈥渆ngineering鈥) approaches in economics, I was a little anxious. I was reassured and delighted when he wrote that he found my work as 鈥渁n original contribution to economics as a branch of the social sciences鈥 (personal correspondence, 17 July 2021).

Kurien鈥檚 work helps us understand the specificities of the Indian economy better. Initially, he used descriptive statistics, and later in life he employed narratives鈥攁ll with the clear purpose of ensuring a good life for all.[2] Let me end this essay with an excerpt from Kurien (1993): 鈥淢y view is that鈥ny serious study of social issues and of society, or of the economy as part of the study of society, is related to two basic queries: 鈥榃hat is my responsibility to myself?鈥 and 鈥榃hat is my responsibility to my neighbour?鈥, precisely because society (and economy) consists of myself and my neighbours and of our interaction鈥 (p. 11).  

ALEX M. THOMAS is Associate Professor of Economics, Azim Premji University, Bengaluru, India. He is the author of Macroeconomics: An Introduction (Cambridge UP, 2021). He is a founding member of the Indian Society for the History of Economic Thought (ISHET) and serves as a council member for the European Society for the History of Economic Thought (ESHET).

Photo: C. T. Kurien, Source: 

This blog post is based on the online presentation I gave at The Reading Club, Department of Economics, MCC on 3rd August 2024; I am grateful to Arun Koshy for inviting me to commemorate Kurien鈥檚 life and work. The content and opinions expressed are mine and are not endorsed by and nor do they necessarily reflect the views of Azim Premji University.

APPENDIX A

YearNameTitle
1982P. RajkumarHousehold Savings, Patterns, Determinants and Motivations
1984Josef JamesUrbanisation and economic change in Tamil Nadu
1985P. UshaLeather Industry in Tamil Nadu: Study of structural change during 1960-80 with special reference to 1973 export trade control policy
1988M. S. S. PandianPolitical economy of agrarian change in Nanchilnadu: the late 19th century to 1939
1988V. K. RamachandranSocio-economic characteristics of agricultural labourers in a vanguard agrarian region
1988S. JanakarajanAspects of market interrelationship in a changing agrarian economy: A Case study from Tamil Nadu
1990K. BharathanThe Handloom Industry in Tamil Nadu: A Study of Organizational structure
1993V. Chandrasekara NaiduEconomic processes and the weaker sections: a Comparative study of two villages in Tamil Nadu
1995J. JeyaranjanA Village Economy in Transition: A Study of the Processes of Change in Iluppakkorai, Tamilnadu, 1960-1985
1995K.T. ThomsonGrowth Technology and levels of living of fishermen in Tamil Nadu

Table: List of PhD students supervised by C. T. Kurien at MIDS

Source:


[1] Under Kurien鈥檚 leadership, the faculty body at MCC restructured their undergraduate curriculum; a report of that exercise, including the syllabus, was published as 鈥樷 (1976) in Economic & Political Weekly (vol. 11, no. 51, pp. 1962-1966). I am grateful to C. Selvaraj for alerting me to this article.

[2] He reviewed a variety of economics books for the magazine Frontline; it would be fruitful for someone to write a paper studying his numerous book reviews. For a list of reviews, see (for drawing my attention to this aspect of Kurien鈥檚 work, I acknowledge Raghunath Nageswaran).

Leave a comment