Why so Hostile? Busting Myths about Heterodox Economics

Call-for-Application-Pluralist-Economics

By Ingrid Harvold Kvangraven and Carolina Alves

鈥淓conomics is unique among the social sciences in having a single monolithic mainstream, which is either unaware of or actively hostile to alternative approaches.鈥 (: 17)

What does heterodox economics mean? Is the label helpful or harmful? Being outside of the mainstream of the Economics discipline, the way we position ourselves may be particularly important. For this reason, many around us shun the use of the term 鈥渉eterodox鈥 and advise against using it. However, we believe the reluctance to use the term stems in part from misunderstandings of (and sometimes disagreement over) what the term means and perhaps disagreements over strategies for how to change the discipline.

In other words, this is an important debate about both identification and strategy. In this blog, we wish to raise the issue in heterodox and mainstream circles, by busting a few common myths about Heterodox Economics – mostly stemming from the orthodoxy. This is a small part of a larger project on defining heterodox economics.

Myth 1: Heterodox Economics is Anything that is Not 鈥淢ainstream鈥
While it is true that many people do see the heterodox as defined in the negative – especially people observing from the mainstream and from outside the discipline – many scholars in the heterodox community also see the term as something positive and proactive, defined by a set of principles (see of definitions). The term dates back to the 1930s (e.g. ), but more recently definitions have been developed by Lee (), Vernengo (), Lawson (), and Dymski ().

Lee (: 8-9) – an important figure in building a heterodox economics community, particularly in the 2000s – saw heterodox economic theory as an 鈥渆mpirically grounded theoretical explanation of the historical process of social provisioning within the context of a capitalist economy鈥. For Lawson (, ch. 3), heterodox economics is best characterized by pluralism at the level of method, coupled with a declared ontology of openness, relationality process, and totalities, in contrast to mainstream economics which is characterised in terms of its enduring reliance upon methods of mathematical modelling, expressed in the mathematical deductivism and its 鈥榣aws鈥 or 鈥榰niformities,鈥 interpreted as correlations or regularities.

Vernengo () argues that heterodox economics is centrally about understanding reproduction of society, that the production and distribution of the social surplus is central for their theories, and that effective demand is valid in the long run (which means that the limits to accumulation are mostly political). Going back to classical political economy, distribution is determined exogenously by social and institutional conditions (e.g. the wage is determined by the bargaining position of labor and the rate of profit is influenced by the interest rate, which is influenced by the central bank).

Lee always to do Economics in a pluralistic and integrative manner and to be responsible and open-minded economists. Openness to alternative methods also gives a much larger space for classes, gender, institutions, instability, uncertainty, exploitation, power asymmetries, distributional conflicts and ecological issues. In a similar manner, Mearman and Guizzo () see heterodox economics as a pluralist community with a diversity of origins, purposes, and standards for economic reasoning, ranging amongst others from history and philosophy of economics, to modelling, community organising, and policymaking.

We see heterodox economics as a study of production and distribution of economic surplus, including the role of power relations in determining economic relationships, a study of economic systems, and tendencies associated with it, and the employment of theories that have these issues at their core, such as Classical Political Economy, Marxian Economics, Feminist Economics, Institutional Economics, and Keynesian Economics. As reality is not static, we deem it as crucial to constantly think and rethink the nature and appropriateness of these theories and methods.

Now, you may think these definitions are too complex, that defining it in the negative is just easier, more practical? Well, it turns out that is not straightforward either, as defining the boundaries for 鈥榤ainstream鈥 Economics is not simple (see ).The defines the field as the study of scarcity, the study of how people use resources to respond to incentives, or the study of decision-making. Others yet define the mainstream by its method (see e.g. or Bandiera ), which can in turn be distinguished from the open systems approach of the heterodoxy.

Recognizing that heterodox economists may be united in their critique of orthodox economics does not mean they are defined by this common position (in fact, scholars in many other disciplines also reject orthodox economics, but this does not mean they are automatically heterodox economists).

So is Austrian Economics heterodox? This is obviously up for debate, and many Austrian economists will indeed identify as heterodox solely on the basis that many of them are excluded from the mainstream or have a different understanding of categories such as equilibrium and uncertainty. However, many heterodox communities would not include Austrians on either epistemological (Austrians tend to adhere to marginalism, see e.g. ) or sociological bases (they are not a part of our research communities, which includes academic institutions, journals, and conferences).

Table 1: Schools of Economic Thought
HeteredoxDiagram

Source: Marc Lavoie鈥檚 .

Myth 2: It is 鈥渉ip鈥 to be Heterodox

The Economist once ran a story 鈥鈥 (similar claims have been made elsewhere too, for example in ). Well, yes, it is true that the use of the term has been on the rise in the 1990s and the 2000s (as documented by , see figure below). There are lots of books popping up using 鈥渉eterodox鈥 in their book titles. (2014: 6) writes that 鈥渟ince the 1990s, but even more so since the mid-2000s, the term 鈥渉eterodox鈥 has become increasingly popular to designate the set of economists who view themselves as belonging to a community of economists distinct from the dominant paradigm鈥.

Figure 1: Google Ngram for 鈥淗eterodox Economics,鈥 1870-2008

pasted image 0

But an increased use of the term does not mean that heterodox work has been accepted in the core of the Economics field. There has not been substantial change in the field since the global financial crisis (see , and ) let alone more inclusivity or openess (e.g. in top journals, hiring practices, prizes or teaching). While there has been some self-critique within the mainstream (e.g. critique of DSGE by and ), this does not mean that alternative theories, such as Post-Keynesian theory or Marxian theory, are now considered to be valid economic theories by top Economics institutions. As observes, the financial crisis had little impact on how the academic orthodoxy in Economics is constructed and reproduced.

Meanwhile, since the crisis, it seems that many concepts developed within a heterodox framework have been incorporated and appropriated by mainstream scholars, adapting them to mainstream frameworks, without any acknowledgment of those concepts鈥 heterodox origin (as highlighted by , among others).

Heterodox Economics is getting traction outside of Economics, though. We can publish in top journals of other fields (e.g. Politics, Geography, Sociology, Philosophy, Development), we can get media coverage in The Financial Times (e.g. prominent heterodox scholars such as , and ), and we can get jobs at top universities, such as University of Cambridge, LSE and Columbia University – but outside of Economics departments (you tend to find heterodox economists at institutes, centers, management schools, and non-Economics social science departments). In the US, many heterodox economists end up teaching at liberal arts colleges. (Note that in some non-Western countries, heterodox economists may get jobs in top Economics departments as they are not as marginalized – this is for example the case in Brazil, see ).

It is true that Heterodox Economics is popular among students (e.g. ), the public, and non-economists, but claiming that it is 鈥渉ip鈥 to be heterodox can be offensive to heterodox economists, as it suggests complete oblivion to the exclusion from our own field that we as heterodox economists historically have faced and continue to face. How many times has it not happened to us that someone within the dominant paradigm says: 鈥淲ell, you鈥檙e not really doing Economics 迟丑辞耻驳丑鈥︹赌?

Myth 3: The Mainstream Is Already Heterodox

Some claim that the mainstream is already heterodox (e.g. Diane Coyle 2007, David Colander 2009, and Colander et al. 2010). These scholars argue that the inclusion of endogenous growth theory, behavioral and experimental economics, complexity economics and other theoretical innovations have reduced the dominance of neoclassical economics (for comprehensive responses to this claim, see , and ). While these developments may give a perception of diversity within the mainstream, as Stilwell () points out, the core still relies on neoclassical ideas such as methodological individualism and systemic stability produced through market forces. There may be a 鈥榗utting edge鈥 which breaks with some orthodox assumptions, as Vernengo () puts it, but it is this part of the mainstream that allows the mainstream to sound reasonable when talking about reality and is therefore plays an important role in maintaining its dominance.

It is evident that there is some extent of pluralism in mainstream Economics, especially with regards to models and different forms of minor deviations from neoclassical economics (e.g. New Keynesian Economics, New Classical Economics, New Institutional Economics, Behavioral Economics). Nevertheless, it must also be acknowledged that there continues to be monism in terms of theoretical starting points, methodological approach, and in attitude to methodological alternatives (see also ).

Critique of the field being met with the defense of the field鈥檚 already existing pluralism thus ignores the actual wide plethora of theories and methodologies that exist in Economics outside the mainstream. Furthermore, these theoretical innovations have not in any shape or form replaced neoclassical economics as the cornerstone of Economics curricula across the world, even if they may be taken as electives down the line in the course of an Economics degree. In short, the developments are neither radical nor transformative.

Myth 4: Heterodox economists are Just Lefties Upset with Neoliberalism

Often, the mainstream of the field is described as neutral, while the heterodoxy is described as ideological. Those believing in such a statement would be surprised to learn from Myrdal (1953) that the development of economic thought has always and everywhere been political, as politics and economics are closely intertwined. There鈥檚 a recognition within all heterodox schools of thought that Economics is inherently political. This does not mean all heterodox economists will agree on politics, but they will usually agree that market solutions do not lead to 鈥渘atural鈥 or 鈥渙ptimal鈥 outcomes.
Dismissing heterodox Economics as a political project is common, which completely covers up the politicalness of mainstream Economics, and it assumes motivations among heterodox economists that they cannot prove or validate.This assumption leads journalists to conclude that heterodox economics is more of a 鈥渢antrum鈥 than an actual rigorous intellectual alternative to the mainstream.

However, much of the heterodox critique of the strong bias towards market-based theory and policy runs deeper than a tantrum against neoliberalism or mainstream economic. It boils down to challenging the idea that the market can always lead to the best outcome. Why is the market solution to economic problems the only game in town and everything deviating from it about market failure? This question relates to the long-standing debate on whether or not economics is value free and how it is possible to best promote positive analysis over normative. While economists often attempt to disguise normative conclusions behind positive analysis, subjective factors are inevitably involved in the development of scientific ideas, and these are theory-laden because they are identified from the perspective of a paradigm. Furthermore, for many heterodox economist, this discussion is also about acknowledging pluralism. That is, there are different ways to investigate an economic phenomenon, and competing approaches, methods and theories lead to different policy implications.

Although mainstream economics and neoliberalism should not be seen as synonymous (see , 2019), the assumption that economic decisions reflect free choice and individual preference tends to support conservative economic policy, which – combined with a focus on markets, incentives and market failures – ends up promoting and supporting market fundamentalism. In this process, core aspects of heterodox economics, ranging from power and conflict between labour and capital, to inequality and the role of institutions have been systematically neglected. It is, therefore, not a surprise to see the heterodox critique of neoliberalism overlapping with critique of mainstream economics.

With the above considerations in mind, it becomes clear not only that choosing one theoretical framework and excluding others is political, but also that every theoretical framework is political, including neoclassical economics. Since class conflict is a core element of much of heterodox economic theory, you will find heterodox economists being more explicitly political, as they are more likely to challenge the ethics of distribution within the system of social provisioning. However, as pointed out by , most heterodox economists do not actually practice politics.

Myth 5: Heterodox Economists Will Take Over Once They Are Able to Construct Convincing Enough Models (aka 鈥業t Takes a Model to Beat a Model鈥)

This is perhaps one of the most ridiculous myths about Heterodox Economics, as it completely shies away from the political nature of our discipline. Several big names in the mainstream perpetuate this idea that Heterodox Economics is kept outside of the mainstream of the discipline because it is simply not rigorous or scientific enough (e.g. in with the Financial Times Pontus Rendahl at University of Cambridge likens Heterodox Economics to creationists and alternative medicine). Angus Deaton has made a similar point, arguing that Economics must 鈥,鈥 as if work done by Heterodox Economics is excluded based on its lack of rigor.

This myth is not only problematic because of its positivist and linear view of scientific progress, but we are also concerned with what 鈥榗onvincing modelling鈥 means. There is a vast range of models associated with heterodox economics. See for example, classical-Marxian models, such as , , , , ; Kaleckian models, such as, , ; Kaldorian, Harrodian and Post Keynesian models, such as , , , ; Thirlwall’s models, such as , , ; Stock-flow Consistent models, such as , , , , , and ; and Agent-Based Models, such as , 鈥 to mention a few!

Thus, putting aside the critique of modelling in economics, two questions come to our mind: first, which kind of rigour is claimed within [mainstream] economics? Second: why aren鈥檛 heterodox models accepted as sufficiently rigorous? The battle between the mainstream and heterodox is by no means straightforward. The rules of the games are contested and there is no impartial measure by which success is judged. Contesting the dominant measures of excellence are indeed among the core demands of many heterodox economists.

Following Myrdal鈥檚 (1953) insight that the development of Economics has always been political, it is clear that it is not simply a matter of constructing 鈥榖etter鈥 economic models. The political process is central. As observed in their review of the Cambridge Capital Controversy, for example, while Cambridge, Massachusetts lost the theoretical debate, they won the hegemony (this was even recognized by the Cambridge, Massachusetts side, see e.g. ). Consequently, scholars working in the tradition of Cambridge, England are now excluded from the field (e.g. Post-Keynesians, Kaleckians, Sraffians, Marxians).

Furthermore, the official university research evaluation processes (e.g. the Research Excellence Framework (REF) in the UK) marginalize non-mainstream approaches, thereby operating to compound many of the problems mentioned so far (Lee et al. , Stilwell ). As research evaluation programs favor mainstream Economics approaches over heterodox ones, teaching also suffers as lecturers hired by Economics departments seeking to maximize their REF score will likely hire only mainstream economists who are likely to publish in top journals (incidentally, have found that teaching has changed little with respect to pluralism since the financial crisis, despite some claims to the contrary). Furthermore, monism in the mainstream makes it less likely that heterodox theories may be picked up by students or policy-makers, thus further compounding the already unfortunate situation. Finally, there have been several studies of the Economics field that show that it is among the most hierarchical academic fields () and that to editors are also important in determining whether a study is published, thus suggesting that success even within the mainstream is not based solely on their internal measure of rigor.

simpsons

Myth 6: Heterodox Economics Is Not Really Economics Though

If Heterodox Economics abandons neoclassical assumptions and formal modeling, why should it be called Economics at all? Couldn鈥檛 it be a part of sociology? This was the argument made by . This view of Economics is ahistorical as it does not recognize that what is heterodox economics today was considered a part of Economics in the past. When Smith, Ricardo, Marx and Keynes did their economic work, they were acknowledged as being a part of the profession. They criticized each others鈥 arguments, assumptions, and theories, but they did not dismiss each other for not being economists. But their ideas have been excluded through a political process.

Ironically, the narrowing of mainstream economics and squeezing of heterodox economists into other departments has come with a push for increased interdisciplinarity. This has led to the odd situation where economists look for collaborators in sociology or politics departments, while maintaining strict definitions of who can be considered an economist. More often than not, economists will collaborate with other social scientists that work within similar traditions (e.g. rational choice theorists in politics or sociology), leading to a narrow form of interdisciplinarity. Further, adding political context or history to mainstream economic analysis does not make it heterodox. Rather than adding interdisciplinarity to social phenomena, we believe it is the nature of social phenomena that bear on the disciplinary or interdisciplinary methods and approaches that are required for their analysis.

Myth #7: Heterodox is too Confrontational. Can鈥檛 we Strive for Pluralism Instead?

Pluralism and heterodox economics aren鈥檛 synonyms. Pluralism is a methodological position that implies that competing theories should be taught alongside each other, be it heterodox or mainstream. Pluralism is not in direct opposition with the mainstream, but rather it tries to broaden the field of Economics.

鈥楶luralism is an 鈥榠n principle鈥 position, based on ontological, epistemological and ethical propositions (as discussed by ), whereas heterodox economics is an alternative way of approaching economic questions that stands as alternatives to the mainstream. Heterodox economists may well be pluralists in principle, as creating space for heterodox economics might in practice result in pluralism. However, fighting for pluralism may not be strategic if our goal is a paradigmatic shift within Economics (a point made on a few months ago).

The Difficulty of a Definition

Defining a whole field, such as Heterodox Economics is not easy, especially not in the social realm (see also ). As with other fields in social science, there will be some disagreement of the precise way to define it, and what kind of scholarship should be included.

Defining heterodox economics needs to be both practically relevant and historically grounded. Practically, it is broadly about seeking to render economics a relevant and inclusive discipline. Here, we don鈥檛 deny the issues raised by related to the need and motives for classification, and its consequences. That is, definitions of heterodox economics usually leads to 鈥渦nwarranted dualism鈥 where scholars create unjustifiably strict and fixed distinctions between the categories. While this might be a useful path to take due to the complexity of the object we are trying to define, it leads us to underplay its complexity for the sake for a simple and clear definition (see also ).

Historically, the concept has been discussed, theorised and applied by a broad and diverse group, starting with Ayers (), and since then there have been contributions from economic methodologists, historians of economic thought, macroeconomists, microeconomists , and philosophers . This is important to understand, as while some might find the definition of the term 鈥榗onfusing,鈥 the source of the confusion might have less to do with the clarity and coherence of any single definition, and more to do with the multiple angles through which the term has been theorised.

With our definition mentioned above, we aim to identify the broader level of principles crossing the diverse discussions on what heterodox economics is. We believe it is important to have a positive definition of heterodox economics to distinguish the field from other social sciences, as well as from the mainstream of the field. Heterodox economists are not sociologists or political scientists, although we are outside of the mainstream of Economics and some heterodox economists may find themselves being employed by such departments. This leads us to our final point…

Why We Should Call Ourselves Heterodox

鈥楤ut we are all economists!鈥 some heterodox economists argue. Why signal that somehow we are different from them? However, we are not sure the 鈥榳e are a big family of economists鈥 strategy is helpful – especially given that the majority of 鈥渙ur family鈥 is excluding us from mainstream arenas. Such a claim indirectly assumes that there are not steep institutional barriers that negatively affect heterodox economists鈥 employment opportunities, funding chances, and their chances to impact the policy making process. The pejorative and dismissive tone towards heterodox scholarship exists, and the question that follows is what we are going to do about it. To avoid acknowledging both the fundamental differences and exclusion is to close door for the progress of the discipline and for young scholars, who are forced to reinvent themselves and find jobs in departments other than economics, contributing to the monolithic character of the discipline.

On a last year, many pros and cons of using the term heterodox came up. We do believe that so far, the pros outweigh the cons. As Stillwell (2016) puts it bluntly: 鈥楲abels matter […]. They construct imagery and signal strategic choices鈥. To us the label signals a strategic choice: Do we try to blend in and pretend that all is fine or do we speak up about the marginalization that is taking place in our field? Self-identifying as heterodox signals to the world that alternative analyses of economic relationships exist – if anything it reinforces the idea that there are different ways to do economics, a point that rests at the core of the argument for pluralism (a big [happy] family after all!). And importantly, it also helps to raise awareness about the fact that these perspectives have been actively excluded from the mainstream over a period of four decades or more.

Does accepting the term heterodox economics mean we accept our marginal disciplinary status? No. On the contrary, we use the term in order to challenge this marginalization. If people find the heterodox label confusing, we should be able to clarify where we are coming from. This is key if we want to change the current state of our profession. If the label is problematic, perhaps it鈥檚 time to de-mystify, clarify and de-problematize it. We understand our colleagues that are scared for their career, or have other strategic reasons, to not speak up, as that is a consequence of the nature of our field. But yet, we encourage more allies to speak up and say we are heterodox – to show the strength and diversity of heterodox economics. The more scholars identity with the term, the more status and acknowledgement heterodox scholarship will get. If we stand together we can show the world what Economics is missing. Come join us outside of the heterodox closet 馃檪

We are grateful to Cleo Chassonnery-Za茂gouche, Danielle Guizzo and Mat铆as Vernengo for helpful comments on an earlier draft.

Ingrid Harvold Kvangraven is a Lecturer in International Development at the University of York.

Carolina Alves is a Joan Robinson Research Fellow in Heterodox Economics at University of Cambridge, the U.K.

Read the article in Spanish .

Sources

Ayres, Clarence Edwin. 1936. 鈥,鈥 American Economic Review 26(1): 224-236.

Barbosa-Filho, Nelson and Taylor, Lance. 2006. , Metroeconomica, 57 (3): 389-411

Bhaduri, Amit and Stephen A. Marglin. 1990. . Cambridge Journal of Economics, 14(4): 375-93.

Caverzasi, Eugenio and Godin, Antonie. 2015. 鈥鈥, European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, 12 (1): 73-92.

Cartwright, Nancy. 1999. .

Cedrini, Mario and Magda Fontana. 2018. 鈥,鈥 Cambridge Journal of Economics 42(2): 427鈥451.

Colander, David. 2009. Moving Beyond the Rhetoric of Pluralism: Suggestions for an 鈥業nside the Mainstream鈥 Heterodoxy, in R. Garnett, E.K. Olsen and M. Starr (eds.), . London and New York: Routledge.

Colander, David., Richard Holt and Barkley Rosser. 2010. 鈥,鈥 Review of Political Economy 16(4): 485-499.

Coyle, Diane. 2007. . Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.

Coyle, Diane. 2013. 鈥,鈥 World Economics Association Curriculum Conference, The Economics Curriculum – A Radical Reformulation.

Dafermos, Yannis & Nikolaidi, Maria & Galanis, Giorgos. 2017. , Ecological Economics, 131(C): 191-207.

Dequech, David. 2018. ,鈥 Journal of Economic Issues 52(4): 904-924.

D鈥橧ppoliti, C. 2018. . Working Paper, No. 57.

Dos Santos, Claudio 2006. 鈥, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30 (4): pp. 541-565.

Dow, Sheila. 1990. . Cambridge Journal of Economics, 14(2): 143鈥157.

Dow, Sheila. 1997. 鈥,鈥 Cambridge Journal of Economics 21(1): 73鈥93.

Dow, Sheila. 2008. 鈥,鈥 The Journal of Philosophical Economics I:2, 73-96.

Dutt, Amitava Krishna. 1984., Cambridge Journal of Economics, 8 (1), pp. 25鈥40.

Epstein, Joshua M and Axtell, Robert L. 1996. . MIT/Brookings Institution.

Foley, Duncan K. 2003. . London: Routledge.

Garc铆a-Molina, Mario and Ru铆z-Tavera, Jeanne Kelly. 2009. , Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 32 (2): 269-290.

Goodwin, Richard, 1967. 鈥楢 growth cycle鈥, in: Carl Feinstein, editor, . Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Hands, D. W. 2011. . Available at SSRN.

Higgins, W. and G. Dow. 2013. . Berne: Peter Lang.

Jo, Ta-Hee and Zdravka Todorova. 2015. 鈥業ntroduction: Frederic S. Lee鈥檚 contributions to heterodox economics,鈥 in Jo, Ta-Hee and Zdravka Todorova (eds). .

Julius, A. J. 2009. , Metroeconomica, 60: 3, 2009

King, J.E. 2013., , Economics and Labour Relations Review 24, pp. 17-31.

Lavoie, Marc. 2009. . Palgrave Macmillan: London.

Lavoie, Marc. 2014. .

Lavoie, Marc and Godley, Wynne (2006) 鈥楩eatures of a realistic banking system within a post-Keynesian stock-flow consistent model, in Mark Setterfield (ed.), , Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, pp. 251-268.

Lawson, Tony 2015. , in Stephen Pratten (ed.) Social Ontology and Modern Economics, London and New York: Routledge.

Lawson, Tony. 2006. 鈥,鈥 Cambridge Journal of Economics 30(4): 483-505.

Lawson, Tony 2013. , Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37 (5): 947鈥983.

Lee, Fred. 2009. .

Lee, Fred. 2017.. Routledge: London.

Lee, Fred and Marc Lavoie (eds). 2012. . Routledge.

Lee, Fred, Xuan Pham and Gyun Gu. 2013. 鈥,鈥 Cambridge Journal of Economics 37(4): 693鈥717.

Kinsella, Stephen and Khalil, Saed. 2011. 鈥楧ebt-Deflation in a Stock Flow Consistent Macromodel鈥, in Dimitri B. Papadimitriou, Gennaro Zezza (eds.), , Palgrave MacMillan.

Mariyani-Squire, E and M. Moussa. 2014. 鈥,鈥 The Journal of Australian Political Economy (75): 194-210.

Mason, J.W. 2018. 鈥,鈥 Jacobin, November 2018.

Mearman, Andrew. 2011. . Review of Radical Political Economics, 43(4): 552鈥561.

Mearman, Andrew, Danielle Guizzo and Sebastian Berger. 2017. 鈥,鈥 Review of Social Economy 76(3): 377-396.

Michell, Jo. 2016.. Critical Finance August 9th 2016.

Pasinetti, Luigi, L. 1962., Review of Economic Studies 29 (4): 267-279

Passarella, Marco. 2012. 鈥鈥, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 83 (3): 570-582.

Tesfatsion, Leigh and Judd, Kenneth L. (eds.). 2006. Elsevier/North-Holland: Amsterdam.

Thornton, Tim. 2015. 鈥Journal of Australian Political Economy 75 (11)-26.

Turner, Paul. 1999. 鈥, International Review of Applied Economics, 13 (1): 41-53.

Setterfield, Mark. 2000. , Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 23(1): 77-105.

Skidelsky, Robert. 2018. . Project Syndicate. Jan, 2018.

Skott, Peter. 2008. , UMASS Amherst Economics Working Papers 2008-12, University of Massachusetts Amherst, Department of Economics.

Skott, Peter and Ryoo, Soon, 2015. , UMASS Amherst Economics Working Papers 2015-13, University of Massachusetts Amherst, Department of Economic.

Steinbaum, Marshall. 2019. 鈥,鈥 The Boston Review February 28, 2019.

Stilwell, Frank. 2016. World Economics Association Newsletter 6(1): 2-6. ( published in Studies in Political Economy, 2012).

Tavani, Daniele. (2012). . Structural Change and Economic Dynamics. ): 117-126

Vera, Leonardo A. (2006) , Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 29 (1): 67-92.

Vernengo, Mat铆as . 2011. 鈥,鈥 Naked Keynesianism May 18th 2011.

Vernengo, Mat铆as. 2014. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics 32(3): 389-396.

Wrenn, M. 2007. . Forum for Social Economics, 36(2): 97鈥108.

Zamparelli, Luca. 2014. , Metroeconomica, 66(2): 243-262.

Zezza, Gennaro (2004) , Levy Economics Institute Working paper no 405.

13 thoughts on “Why so Hostile? Busting Myths about Heterodox Economics

  1. Do you mind if I repost this to the urpe blog?

    On Wed, May 8, 2019 at 8:09 AM 黑料社区 wrote:

    > Ingrid Harvold Kvangraven posted: ” By Ingrid Harvold Kvangraven and > Carolina Alves 鈥淓conomics is unique among the social sciences in having a > single monolithic mainstream, which is either unaware of or actively > hostile to alternative approaches.鈥 (John King 2013: 17) What does > heterodox ” >

    Like

  2. this was very interesting thanks.

    Seems to me there are two possible outcomes we might hope for 鈥 1. the vanquishing of the currently mainstream approach and replacement with currently heterodox approaches or 2. the evolution of the mainstream towards a better place (and happy co-existence with other approaches 鈥 pluralism).

    I am biased here, so take this with that in mind, but 1. seems like a long-shot, because I think the desire to mathematically model purposeful individual (or agents, more generally) behaviour and also explain why certain situations can be self-sustaining (e.g. an equilibrium, broadly interpreted) is going to persist, plus the mainstream is streets ahead with empirical methods (imo). So I think 2. is the more promising objective (and indeed, it鈥檚 why I鈥檇 still consider myself mainstream, despite seeing much in it I would like to change).

    In which case, we are in a bad place. I think. You mention the disparaging and dismissive attitude the (some/most of the) mainstream takes towards the heterodox, how hard it is to get hired / published, and I don鈥檛 dispute that (I鈥檝e noted elsewhere when mainstream work should be citing heterodox work that had the same ideas, earlier), so I completely understand your beef with the mainstream in that regard.

    Unfortunately, it is reciprocated.

    I constantly see heterodox and pluralists write and tweet things that portray mainstream economists as absolute idiots, really dumb and offensive (and most importantly: inaccurate) stuff, all merrily cheered on by team heterodox and/or pluralist. The prominence of individuals like Steve Keen in the movement is an exemplar.

    It鈥檚 a shame (at least I think so) because it makes productive exchanges between the two camps very difficult. But here we are. I don鈥檛 see what鈥檚 going to move us out of this particular equilibrium.

    Liked by 1 person

  3. heterox means “not ortodox” so you could just as well say “unusual” economics. Sound very simple and plain. thats because it is just that

    Like

  4. 鈥淚n the US, many heterodox economists end up teaching at liberal arts colleges.鈥
    I would like to make two points, referring to the U.S. case: (1) studies of the U.S. job market in the economics literature do not find that liberal arts colleges are the bottom of the market in general, as this passage in your otherwise lovely post seems to imply. (2) many U.S. liberal arts colleges also exclude heterodox economists when hiring, while some U.S. universities hire heterodox economists.
    Looking just casually for something on the internet to back up my first point, I searched online for the heck of it and found that this 2013 mainstream study of job market market outcomes for econ Ph.D.s as a function of various variables from the Journal of Labor Research: . This study used a mainstream worldwide ranking of the top 200 academic institutions from the Journal of the European Economic Association at this URL: . The institutional ranking lists Williams College, a highly ranked U.S. liberal arts college, as number 194 in this top 200. (In the study of job market outcomes, top government jobs such as the IMF were given a ranking of 40, and top consulting jobs a ranking of 120. All remaining jobs, obviously including academic jobs out of the top 200, were given a ranking of 300. There are of course thousands of academic institutions in the U.S.)
    I agree that heterodox economists are shut out many of the 鈥渂est鈥 academic jobs in the market by many measures simply because they are heterodox. For example, there have been very few hires of heterodox candidates in the 鈥渢op 20鈥 U.S. universities in the last 40 years. For material on rankings of heterodox departments and journals, one can look to work by Fred Lee and others at the heterodox Economics Network website: . However, the sources there unfortunately only rank Ph.D.-granting institutions, a common kind of study whose ubiquity may mislead readers perhaps about the relevance of liberal arts colleges and the quality and prestige of the jobs they offer. It is unfortunate that the very top-ranked liberal arts colleges do not seem to hire heterodox economists, though few heterodox candidates of course graduate from the 鈥渢op鈥 Ph.D. programs in conventional (orthodox) rankings鈥攁 vicious cycle of sorts.

    Like

  5. [鈥 is a broad umbrella, and some of its ideas stand up to scrutiny better than others.) Alves, a proponent of heterodox economics, says it doesn鈥檛 conform to the idea that there is one way to do economics best. One of the ways [鈥

    Like

  6. I really enjoyed reading this and plan to look at the links and the points raised more in depth. It really sparked a lot of ideas in my head. Some time ago I wrote and presented a paper at an AFIT meeting about why heterodox economics is different in nature from ideas like Intelligent Design. The paper had some flaws and I left it on the drawing board. After reading this, I鈥檓 thinking I may try to go back and pick it up again. My short, off the cuff observation about why mainstream economics is generally hostile to heterodox economics is 1. path dependency and 2. I really do think a lot of it comes down to their comittment to formal mathematical modeling as the test of good theory.

    Like

  7. […] points have long been emphasised by heterodox economists. More government spending on public investment projects and public services, as well as greater […]

    Like

  8. […] points have long been emphasised by heterodox economists. More government spending on public investment projects and public services, as well as greater […]

    Like

  9. […] factorshave long been emphasised by heterodox economists Extra federal authorities prices on public monetary funding jobs and public companies, together […]

    Like

  10. […] applied economics, falling broadly within what can be described as the neoclassical framework and聽the denigration of alternative approaches; and the neglect of and ignorance about economic research and analysis done by scholars who are not […]

    Like

  11. […] applied economics, falling broadly within what can be described as the neoclassical framework and聽the denigration of alternative approaches; and the neglect of and ignorance about economic research and analysis done by scholars who are not […]

    Like

  12. […] heterodox economics means and how and why it is often misunderstood. The talk was based on this blog post and this working paper with my brilliant co-author Carolina […]

    Like

Leave a reply to Coronavirus Recovery- The New Economic Thinking We Need - DeepFind Cancel reply