The Co-evolution of Diversity in Property and Economic Development: Evolutionary Economics and the Vertical Dimension (Part 2)

Having laid out the horizontal dimensions of diversity in property in Part 1, I here offer a critique of the assumption in mainstream economics that all kinds of property institutions need to be or will be transformed into private property to promote economic development. I also reflect on my previous work that applies and develops Darwinian mechanisms of variation, inheritance, and selection鈥攚hich has been extensively discussed in evolutionary biology and evolutionary economics鈥攖o study property regime transformation in China.

While working on , Professor Erik Reinert introduced me to two very important books and encouraged me to think about the relevance of the work of Darwin and Veblen to study property regime transformation in China: by Stephen Jay Gould (1941-2002), Harvard biologist and historian of science; edited by Erik himself and Francesca Viano. Erik also introduced me to the work of evolutionary economists including of Columbia University.

In (1859), Darwin specified three mechanisms of evolutionary change鈥攙ariation, inheritance, and selection. It should be noted that Darwin never liked the word evolution due to 鈥榟is denial of progress as a predictable outcome鈥 (). Gould (1996/2011: 41) argued that 鈥楧arwin鈥檚 revolution should be epitomized as the substitution of variation for essence as the central category of natural reality.鈥 He further argued:

鈥n Plato鈥檚 world, variation is accidental, while essences record a higher reality; in Darwin鈥檚 reversal, we value variation as a defining (and concrete earthly) reality, while averages (our closest operational approach to 鈥渆ssences鈥) become mental abstractions.

In ,  Hodgson (2012: 287) argued that Veblen had contributed to evolutionary and institutional economics by bringing 鈥楧arwinian ideas into the economic arena鈥.

痴别产濒别苍鈥檚 ) definition of institution is dynamic:

Institutions are, in substance, prevalent habits of thought with respect to particular relations and particular functions of the individual and of the community [鈥 The situation of today shapes the institutions of tomorrow through a selective, coercive process, by acting upon men鈥檚 habitual view of things, and so altering or fortifying a point of view or a mental attitude handed down from the past. [鈥 The evolution of society is substantially a process of mental adaptation on the part of individuals under the stress of circumstances which will no longer tolerate habits of thought formed under and conforming to a different set of circumstances in the past.

Changing socio-economic contexts may shift and reframe 鈥榩erceptions and dispositions within individuals鈥 and give rise to new 鈥榟abits of thought and behaviour鈥 (Hodgson 2012: 287) and thus new forms of institution. Veblen (1899/2007) termed this phenomenon 鈥榮election鈥 as 鈥榮elective adaptation鈥. Although Veblen 鈥榙id not make the context, criteria or mechanisms of selection entirely clear鈥, he 鈥榞enerally saw institutions as units of selection in a process of economic evolution鈥 (Hodgson 2012: 291).

In terms of 鈥榗o-evolution鈥, it is the 鈥榮ignature term鈥 of Richard Nelson. His 1982 book with Sidney Winter represented the start of the neo-Schumpeterian wave. Most evolutionary economists use the term 鈥榗o-evolution鈥. Further, the Darwinian mechanisms have been extensively discussed by biologists, institutional and evolutionary economists, for example (discussing creation, selection and variation) and (discussing variation, selection, and niche construction).

Bringing Darwinian ideas and Veblenian institutions to the analysis of property regime transformation, I completed a working paper in 2015 and argued that the works of Darwin and Veblen also contribute to studies of property. The (Darwinian) transformation of property can be elucidated not only by drawing analogies to the Darwinian mechanisms of variation, inheritance, and selection, but also by broadening the scope of the Darwinian framework, from the biological world to human interactions in society.

There are key mechanisms for understanding and analysing the co-evolution of diversity in property and economic development:

  1. Variation: the existence of diversity in property in accordance with dynamic socio-economic conditions.
  2. Inheritance: the persistence and continuity of the old property regime despite legal and political changes.
  3. Selection: the formation of new forms of property more adapted to socio-economic contexts.

Institutions are created or modified to selectively adapt to the changes in socio-economic contexts. But institutions which enable economic development are often brought about by emulation and innovation beyond adaptation. I will leave the discussion of emulation to my next blog posts and focus on innovation here.

To further illustrate the importance of innovation for economic development, we need to bring in Schumpeterian institutions, which are concerned with the importance of innovation in generating new knowledge and modes of production, which helps move the economic activities to the next 鈥榮tage鈥 or 鈥榩aradigm鈥 (). The relevant discussion of Schumpeterian institutions can be found in my previous blog post on 鈥業nstitutions, Economic Development, and China鈥檚 Development Policy for Escaping Poverty鈥.

When we bring in Schumpeterian institutions to Darwinian mechanisms and Veblenian institutions discussed above, the third mechanism can be developed as selection: the formation of new forms of property more adapted to socio-economic contexts; for economic development, selection need to be prompted by emulation and innovation.

All the three mechanisms can be found in China鈥檚 long-term property (in rural land) regime transformation (see Part 1).

Variation (diversity) existed in all four periods. The introduction of collective ownership to rural China (1956-1978) by political forces did result in the decrease of diversity in property, therefore reducing the degree of resilience of the property regime in instances of natural disasters and economic and political crises.

The attempt to eliminate diversity in property, however, only lasted for a relatively short span of time, as the political programmes could not change the mode of agricultural production, which still relied on household-based productions. Fundamental aspects of the old property regime persisted and continued, despite alterations, if the economic conditions have not been fundamentally changed (inheritance).

The household responsibility systema development-promoting institution鈥攚as introduced in the late 1970s. This rural land management system was adapted to household-based agricultural productions (selection). Once farmers had discharged their duty to meet the grain quota imposed by the state, they could retain their additional production鈥攖he grain produced over and above the required quota.

Further, beyond being a property institution formed through selection adaptation, the household responsibility system was also an innovative property institution in the period between the late 1970s and 1980s, which gave incentives to individual farmers and their households to engage in farming within collective ownership of rural land (innovation).

In the 1990s techno-economic development in agricultural production, however, began to require a new mode of production for promoting cooperation and consolidated/industrialised farming. The household responsibility system, which was once an innovative initiative that promoted economic development, had come to function as a roadblock to further development. New development-promoting property institutions were created in the 1990s and further developed to promote the new mode of production, initiating a process of creative destruction.

In , I further clarified three interrelated terms: .

Property regime transformation in the broad sense does not indicate either a clear trend or a foreseeable outcome; it need not be progressive. By contrast, innovative property transformation with reference to Schumpeterian institutions conveys a positive connotation of enabling economic development and structural change, which may not be a smooth process. Property evolution in the broad sense conveys a positive connotation (it may even contain a teleological element), but not necessarily the identical form of connotation found in innovative property transformation.

In conclusion, the transformation of property is neither a spontaneous process nor a process solely prompted by external factors; it does not move towards a predictable outcome. Diversity in property and economic development co-evolve. We need to examine changing contexts, in particular techno-economic change over time rather than a linear, normative series of changes such as from communal property to private property, as the inevitable result of property regime transformation.

Ting Xu is Professor of Law at Essex Law School, University of Essex. Her research focuses on comparative property law; Chinese law; law, governance and development; and political economy. She tweets at .

3 thoughts on “The Co-evolution of Diversity in Property and Economic Development: Evolutionary Economics and the Vertical Dimension (Part 2)

  1. i read this all article carefully. this article is most valueable for me and every one. i recommend the other peoples to read this value able content. further i suggest that if anyone want to read more about the economy then visit . Thanks

    Like

  2. […] and comprises two parts dealing with the key concepts (Part 1) and mechanisms (Part 2) for evaluating the co-evolution of diversity in property and economic development. I argue that […]

    Like

  3. […] This article first appeared on 黑料社区 and is reproduced on the ELR Blog with permission and thanks. You can read the original post here. […]

    Like

Leave a reply to msanjumbwp Cancel reply